Friday, 8 December 1995

CE N'EST QU'UN DEBUT...

New Statesman & Society leader, 8 December 1995

The crisis in France marks the beginning of what promises to be a protracted battle over the future of western Europe's welfare systems


A re-run of May 1968 it is not. Despite the superfi­cial similarities – an unpopular right-wing gov­ernment, students and workers on the streets of Paris, the riot police wading in with truncheons and tear-gas – the current crisis in France is not a case of history repeating itself.

May 1968 was a revolt against the tedium and powerlessness of life in a bureaucratic welfare-capitalist con­sumer society in which steady growth and full employ­ment were taken for granted. December 1995 is a revolt against a government's plans to remove substantial parts of the welfare safety net from a society that has long seen steady growth and full employment as things of the past. 

But if that makes the current crisis rather less exciting for left- wingers brought up on 1968’s dreams of a self-managed socialist revolution, it is in many ways just as profound. The level of public spending on welfare in west European societies is the single biggest issue those societies face today, and the events of the past fortnight have brought it into sharp relief. The government of Prime Minister Alain Juppe says that France must reduce its generous welfare provision if it is to compete in the modern global economy: there is no alternative to the rigours of the marketplace. The unions say that they have paid for their benefits through taxation and don't want to give them up. As NSS goes to press, the chances of compromise seem remote.

What gives the crisis its particular edge is that the gov­ernment has been hoist with its own petard – or rather one it was happy to inherit from the previous socialist administration. For all Juppe's talk, international com­petitiveness isn't all that his austerity programme is about: he wants to cut welfare spending because, accord­ing to the Maastricht treaty, he needs to reduce the public debt if France is to participate in European monetary union.

But the reason that the public debt is so great is that growth is so low and unemployment so high – and the most important reason for this is that the franc has been overvalued as a result of a policy of pegging its value to that of the Deutschmark, the purpose of which is of course to ensure that France is able to participate in Euro­pean monetary union in 1999.

The stakes are thus extremely high. If Juppe gives in to the strikers and demonstrators and withdraws his austerity programme, his political career will be over and President Jacques Chirac's room for manoeuvre in his remaining six years in the Elysee palace will be severely constrained. More important, if the Juppe plan is killed off, France will be unable to meet the Maastricht treaty criteria on public debt until well into the next century – and the money markets will almost certainly force a devaluation of the franc into the bargain. Given that the Germans don't see any point in EMU unless France is involved – they only agreed to it because Francois Mitter­rand insisted on it as the price for political union – that would almost certainly destroy the prospects for EMU before the millennium.

It is not necessary to be a Eurosceptic to consider that this might not be quite the disaster that some commenta­tors think it would be. The timetable for monetary union envisaged in the Maastricht treaty was always ambitious, and the treaty always involved serious pain for all the larger economies locked into it apart from Germany.

Many on the left who backed Maastricht in 1992, including NSS, argued that the deflationary effects of the process envisaged by the treaty – caused by budget deficit cutting and over-valued currencies – necessitated serious compensatory measures organised through the EU if it was not all to end in tears. But, thanks largely to the most Eurosceptic government of all, our own, the best chance of such measures, the Euro-Keynesianism outlined by Jacques Delors as president of the European Commission, was scuppered last year. Since then, even the Europhile left has started to have doubts about the conditions and timetable laid down by Maastricht. A vic­tory for the strikers and demonstrators would, at the very least, force a welcome rethink about how we secure mon­etary union.

What it would not do, however, is end the argument about how much western Europe can afford to spend the welfare state if it is to compete internationally. Like the French strikers, NSS has always been sceptical of the idea that a welfare state largely funded through income and consumer taxation is such a disincentive to invest­ment that it must be constantly pared back. We can spend, in short, if we tax. But defending this view is likely to get increasingly difficult in years to come. The French crisis is just the beginning of a protracted struggle over the very nature of the society in which we live.